Archive | February, 2013

The underbelly of FDI-driven investment

26 Feb

P1000213

Ok, there’s a lot of a good stuff with FDI in Eastern Europe. Chief among them is that the region now has more complex and higher value-added exports. Yet the crisis brought to the fore a long list of issues. Here are several examples, drawn from the case of Romania, which is not that different from East-central Europe:

By 2008 Romania began to look more like Poland than the small export oriented economies of Slovakia, the Czech Republic or Hungary when it comes to the makeup of FDI flows: three times more investment went into commodities and banking than on complex products. In the ranking of export complexity done MIT’s Economic Observatory, the level of complexity of Romanian exports has gone from a low level in the early 2000s to ranking close to the Netherland’s, lower that that of Hungary, the Czech Republic or Slovakia as well as higher not only relative to Bulgaria and the Baltics, but also than in Spain and Portugal.

The share of FDI in exports grew, as did exports themselves. By the end of that decade, Austrian, German, French and Italian firms (in this order) accounted for about two thirds of Romania’s exports. Of the top 100 exporters (who cover half of all exports), 96 were subsidiaries of multinationals in 2011. Thanks to such firms, exports boomed: compared to the 1990s, exports in 2010s were 600 percent bigger.

The Great Recession brought many problems to the fore, though. First, FDI is pro-cyclical source of investment. During the crisis it dropped from an average of 6 billion a year to around 2 billion a year after 2009. Second, deindustrialization was not arrested. Every year between 2001 and 2008 the share of industry in GDP shrunk by nearly 1 percent a year and industrial employment continued to decline. This became worse during the crisis.While the car industry boomed, the steel industry shrunk by a third, for example and both industries are foreign-owned.

Third, strategic FDI investments were exposed as living in part on government dole. Once removed the vast net of perks with which FDI was attracted, some multinationals confronted the Romanian government and society with a rude awakening to the reality of disloyal capital. A few high employment multinationals cut down their operations as a result of falling demand in Western Europe. Others (Finnish Nokia and Russian Mechel) simply used up the FDI incentives and then swiftly moved out to economies with even lower wages. Moreover, the fiscal crisis of the state forced out revelations that the oligopoly of five Western European energy companies saved about 250 million euro by not investing in the modernization of the power grid infrastructure they purchased with a discount in 2005-08, often causing the power infrastructure to be increasingly disfunctional.

Fourth, the piecemeal privatization of large SOEs that had been designed as integrated systems led to dramatic deindustrialization episodes in some parts of the country. Take the examples of Arpechim, one of the refineries owned by Petrom, the national oil company sold to Austrian-owned OMV. During the crisis OMV found this refinery to be unprofitable and decided to shut it down. But since Arpechim had been designed by socialist planners to provide Oltchim, the biggest plastics plant in Eastern Europe, with cheap raw materials, the shutdown of Arpechim means the death of state-owned Oltchim.

Finally, privatizations of the electricity grid were associated with expensive inputs for non-protected corporates and consumers and creating incentives for the central bank to have a procyclical interest rate policy. Thus, since 2005 the price of electric bills doubled, a significant cost increase for doing business in Romania.

The last decade almost seemed like the beginning of a turnaround and FDI seemed like the superhero of an industrial renaissance. Ironically, the socialist planner and the foreign investor had the same preferences: as in 1970s and 1980s, the bulk of FDI was invested in energy, chemicals, means of transportation, industrial equipment, mining and steels. Textiles and footwear, the erstwhile export niche of the Romanian economy, received only 1.4 percent of FDI, three times less than the IT sector. Manufacturing attracted most FDI (44 percent), as the low wage army of labor with solid engineering skills made possible in part by the modernist educational philosophy of Romanian socialism made possible a boom of Western investment in manufacturing, from cars to aircraft parts. But the crisis has showed that FDI-centric development needs to be reexamined. And soon.

Views from the top

26 Feb

What fiscal crisis?

24 Feb

Screen Shot 2013-02-23 at 7.58.18 PMTwo sentences from a Tax Justice report to keep in mind when you hear that there are no money to pay for a dignified way out of the crisis:

“A significant fraction of global private financial wealth — by our estimates, at least $21 to $32 trillion as of 2010 — has been invested virtually tax-free through the world’s still- expanding black hole of more than 80 “offshore” secrecy jurisdictions. We believe this range to be conservative, for reasons discussed below.”

Full report here

Click to access The_Price_of_Offshore_Revisited_-_22-07-2012.pdf

The global economy is still a highly centralized affair

23 Feb

737 players may control 80 percent of multinationals

Screen Shot 2013-02-23 at 6.02.49 PM

Reinventing the domestic

21 Feb

A recent Erste Bank report says this about Eastern Europe:
“Endogenous sources of productivity will become more important, as the stimulus via FDI and exports may be moderate in the coming years if the crisis drags on. The challenge for Central and Eastern Europe in general is to manage the transition from imported productivity gains to endogenous sources of innovation as drivers of growth.”

http://blogs.ft.com/beyond-brics/2013/02/20/cee-stop-imitating-start-innovating/#axzz2LSPLWuQh

In other words: you Eastern dupes, make sure you discover some version of the neo-developmental state to kickstart innovation. Read Bill Janeway and see that what did it most of the time was the state, not heroic venture capitalists. Oh, did we tell you the opposite before the crisis? That it is all best left to the markets? Oh, well….

Watch Helicopter Money!

21 Feb

Screen Shot 2013-02-20 at 10.49.57 PM

It’s a sharp new blog by Daniela Gabor, a brilliant economist at the Bristol Business School. Expect direct punches powered by heterodox critiques of the existing financial order.

http://helicoptermoney.blogspot.co.uk/

On the concept of helicopter money and its distinctiveness relative to “printing money” see http://blogs.ft.com/gavyndavies/2013/02/17/helicopters-can-be-dangerous/

The Naked Captains of Finance

6 Feb

Anat Admati & Martin Hellwig Feb 3, 2013 6:30 PM ET

In Hans Christian Andersen’s famous tale “The Emperor’s New Clothes,” two tailors offer to provide the emperor with beautiful and very special clothes. They claim the clothes will be invisible to people who are stupid or unfit for their jobs. The emperor orders a full set.

When he sends his ministers to monitor the tailors, the ministers don’t see anything, but out of fear of being considered incompetent, none of them admits this and instead they extol the splendors of the invisible clothes. The emperor finds his new attire invisible, yet not wanting to appear stupid, praises the nonexistent items. When he tours his capital wearing the “clothes,” onlookers also admire them, even though they don’t see anything. Only when a child shouts: “The emperor has no clothes!” does everyone admit that the emperor is, in fact, naked.

Banks have a similar mystique. There is a pervasive myth that banks are different — special, somehow — from all other companies and industries in the economy. Anyone who questions this is at risk of being declared incompetent.

In fact, many claims made by leading bankers and banking experts, including academics, have as much substance as the emperor’s new clothes. But most people don’t challenge these claims, even as the claims affect policy. The specialists’ confidence is too intimidating. Even people who know better fail to speak up. The public is taken in.
“Costly” Regulation

Some bankers may admit to mistakes leading to the financial crisis that began in 2007, but they portray the crisis as a fluke or as an accident that is highly unlikely to recur in our lifetimes. It would be costly and wasteful, they claim, to tighten regulation to forestall an event that might happen once in 100 years. Tighter regulation, we are warned, would interfere with what banks do to support the economy, and this would have serious, unintended consequences.

Take bank borrowing. Excessive borrowing was identified as a major factor in the financial crisis. Bankers sometimes admit this. Nevertheless, the banking industry fights aggressively against tighter restrictions on bank borrowing. The constant refrain is that too much tightening would harm economic growth.

This is a typical bugbear, suggesting that we must choose between economic growth and financial stability. After all, who would be in favor of a regulation that reduces growth and therefore might have negative effects for all? In fact, the history of financial crises and instability, including the recent crisis, has shown that the greatest damage to bank lending and growth occurs when banks become distressed from having borrowed too much and lost on their investments.

Why would restrictions on bank borrowing have any effect on bank lending whatsoever? One argument was given in 2010 by the British Bankers’ Association, which claimed that new regulations would require U.K. banks to “hold an extra 600 billion pounds of capital that might otherwise have been deployed as loans to businesses or households.” To anyone who doesn’t know what the regulation is about, this argument may sound plausible. In fact, it is nonsensical and false.

The nonsense is due to the misuse of the word “capital.” In the language of banking, this word refers to the money the bank has received from its shareholders or owners. This is to be distinguished from the money it has borrowed. Banks use both borrowed and unborrowed money to make their loans and other investments. Unborrowed money is the money that a bank has obtained from its owners if it is a private bank, or from its shareholders if it is a corporation, along with any profits it has retained.
Unborrowed Money

Elsewhere in the economy, this type of funding is referred to as equity. In banking, it is called capital. Capital regulation requires that a sufficient fraction of a bank’s investments or assets be funded with unborrowed money. This is similar to the requirement that a homebuyer make a minimum down payment when buying a house. Having a minimal ratio of unborrowed funds relative to total assets is a way to limit the share of assets that is funded by borrowing.

Because unborrowed funds are obtained without any promise to make specific payments at particular times, having more equity enhances the bank’s ability to absorb losses on its assets. From the statement of the British Bankers’ Association, however, we wouldn’t guess that capital requirements are about how much a bank borrows. The statement makes it appear as if capital were a cash reserve — a pile of cash that banks hold that can’t be used to make loans.

In fact, capital regulation does not tell banks what to do with their funds or what they should hold. It tells banks only what portion of the funds they use that must be unborrowed. Saying that new regulations would require U.K. banks to “hold an extra 600 billion pounds of capital” is nonsense. The implication that loans to businesses or households are automatically reduced by that 600 billion pounds is false. Capital is not a rainy-day fund.

The confusion about the term “bank capital” is pervasive. Numerous media reports say that banks must “set aside” capital to satisfy new regulations. References to capital reserves suggest that the regulation forces banks to hold cash that sits idly in the bank’s tills without being put to work in the economy. A bank lobbyist is quoted as saying, “A dollar in capital is one less dollar working in the economy.”

Another line of argument against increased capital requirements is that capital — that is, equity — is expensive and that if banks must have more equity, their costs would increase. This mantra is so self-evident to banking specialists that they usually see no need to justify it.
Hating Equity

But why do banks hate equity so much and view it as expensive? In what exact sense is it expensive, and what does this mean for society and for policy?

We can test this argument by comparing banks to other corporations. Corporations in most industries are free to borrow as much as they want if they can find a lender. Yet there is no other sector in which corporations borrow nearly as much as banks do. For the vast majority of nonfinancial corporations in the U.S., borrowing represents less than 50 percent of assets. Some highly successful companies don’t borrow at all.

By contrast, debt often accounts for more than 90 percent of bank assets. For some large European banks, the fraction is even higher, above 97 percent. It was that high for some major U.S. investment banks before 2007, as well as for the mortgage giants Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, which were bailed out. The new regulations that the banking industry complains about would still allow debt to fund 97 percent of bank assets.

If a company can count on being bailed out by the government when it can’t pay its debts and if its creditors don’t worry much about a default, creditors would be happy to lend to the company. The company would find that borrowing is cheap and, by comparison, other ways to fund investments, such as equity, would be expensive.

The interest that the company would have to pay on its debt wouldn’t reflect its true default risk because that is partly borne by the taxpayer. From the perspective of the banks, therefore, borrowing is cheap.

Among the lobbying cries is the suggestion that regulation should not harm “our” banks in global competition and thus cannot be tighter than regulations elsewhere. This, too, is an invalid argument.

A country’s public policy shouldn’t be concerned about the success of banks or other firms if that success is achieved through taxpayer subsidies or by exposing the public to excessive risks — for example, the risk of pollution or a financial crisis.
Systemically Important

Why should we care so much about the safety of banks and about how much banks borrow? The damage from a bank’s getting into difficulties from excessive borrowing can be great, affecting many beyond those directly involved.

The potential damage is especially large when the bank is a systemically important financial institution like JPMorgan Chase & Co. or Deutsche Bank AG, with massive operations all over the globe. Excessive borrowing by such banks exposes all of us to risks, costs and inefficiencies that are entirely unnecessary.

The too-big-to-fail problem for banks is greater today than it was in 2008. Since then, the largest U.S. banks have become much larger. On March 31, 2012, the debt of JPMorgan Chase was valued at $2.13 trillion and that of Bank of America Corp. at $1.95 trillion, more than three times the debt of Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. The debt of the five largest U.S. banks totals about $8 trillion. These figures would be even larger under European accounting rules.

This situation makes it all the more important to prevent scenarios in which governments must choose between letting a major institution fail or committing to an expensive bailout. One approach is to try to create mechanisms that would allow large banks to fail without disrupting the economy or requiring public support. Although useful efforts have been made in this direction, this remains a challenge for global banks. Even the best resolution mechanism is likely to be disruptive and costly.

The present situation is perverse. It is as if we were to subsidize the chemical industry to intentionally pollute rivers and lakes. Such subsidies would encourage additional pollution. If the industry were asked to limit the pollution, it would complain that its costs would increase. Would such complaints make us tolerate the pollution?

Subsidizing banks to borrow excessively and take on so much risk that the entire banking system is threatened is just like subsidizing and encouraging companies to pollute when they have clean alternatives.

(Anat Admati is a professor of finance and economics at the Stanford Graduate School of Business and Martin Hellwig is a director at the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods in Bonn. This is the first in a series of three excerpts from their new book, “The Bankers’ New Clothes: What’s Wrong With Banking and What to Do About It,” to be published Feb. 24 by Princeton University Press. The opinions expressed are their own.)
Source: http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2013-02-03/emperors-of-banking-have-no-clothes.html

Models and Morons

5 Feb

The brave new collaborative economy

4 Feb

Screen Shot 2013-02-04 at 9.54.22 AM

So you thought the new, collaborative economy is this new cool space for hipsters like you, not the stuffy old safe job of your boring papa. Not so, say some insiders. FT’s Izabella Kaminska turns on the flashlight on this reality and even ventures with some solutions:

“Something new is happening with the collaborative economy. Instead of creating new industries that are based on mechanization and thus require the production of new robots and machines as in the 20th century, what we are witnessing with the collaborative economy is a shift from jobs towards unpaid labor from a crowd of volunteers. Take open-source softwares or Wikipedia for instance, and imagine this for the whole economy. Long story short, this is not about less work, but about having fewer paid positions.

Which gets back to the point about the monopolisation of profits in such a world and how to equitably distribute the wealth that’s created via the collaborative process.

In other words, is it fair for a corporate that depends entirely on voluntary input for its capital returns, to suck up those profits entirely for itself? Or should that wealth somehow be shared amongst the collaborative community? Are these corporates becoming rentiers as some argue, or as others might counter social utilities, which need to make money to cover costs of operation and infrastructure.

There is one potential solution. You could call it the “common agricultural policy” response. A model in which people are compensated by the government for staying out of the “financially compensated” workforce if their occupational field is oversupplied and suffering the effects of overproduction and capacity, and thus become free to deploy leisure time as they see fit with no need for compensation.

Another way of achieving the same result, of course, is simply by debasing the rents collected by industry via permanent money creation — so as to offset the disproportional wealth effect on today’s tech rentiers as well as older generations, which all things relative, appear to have over-benefited from the first mover advantage associated with their era. So not dissimilar to what’s happening now, but with one important difference: that the newly created money flows directly to spending individuals rather than corporates, savers and banks, who do anything but spend.”

More here
http://ftalphaville.ft.com/2013/01/02/1318343/why-a-free-market-changes-everything/